1.2 Limitations of the Barter System

Artistic drawing of two people trading through barter in an abandoned market - Bitcoin Foundations
We discussed why trade was necessary in our previous article. Here we’ll cover trade in its most primitive form, the bartering system, and how money was born out of necessity. Bartering is a method of exchange that relies on the direct trade of goods and services rather than the use of money. It has been used for centuries as a way for people to obtain the products and services they need. While the bartering system has its benefits, it is not without significant limitations.1 In this article, we will explore some of the main limitations of the bartering system and how money solved them.

Multiple prices

The bartering system introduces the issue of multiple prices per good.[2] In an economy of two items, apples and pears, there will be one exchange rate. Apples priced in pears (e.g. 1 apple for 2 pears) and the reciprocal to that would be pears priced in apples (0.5 apples per pear). When you increase the number of goods in such an economy, the number of exchange rates increases substantially. If we have four goods (apples, pears, bananas, and oranges), the number of exchange rates increases to six. 

  • Apples priced in Pears
  • Apples priced in Bananas
  • Apples priced in Oranges
  • Pears priced in Bananas
  • Pears priced in Oranges
  • Bananas priced in Oranges

If we have one hundred goods to trade, that would result in 4950 exchange rates. 

No. of exchange rates = n x (n-1)/2

n = number of goods

Using the formula above, for your average Walmart store that holds about 10,000 goods, you’d be looking at an eye-watering 49,995,000 exchange rates. In small economies, a handful of exchange rates are manageable. The bartering system would not be able to scale to a global economy (let alone a single Walmart one).

With the use of money, there will be one exchange rate per good.

  • 2 goods = 2 exchange rates
  • 6 goods = 6 exchange rates
  • 100 goods = 100 exchange rates
  • 10,000 goods = 10,000 exchange rates

Coincidence of Wants

The bigger issue with bartering, and the main problem money solves, is the coincidence of wants problem. To successfully arrange a trade you need to find a trading partner who has what you want and wants what you have. If one of those conditions is not met, the trade will not take place. It could simply be that one partner just doesn’t want a specific item or more practical issues such as non-coincidence of scale, time frame, or location such as in the examples below.2

Coincidence of Scale

Artistic drawing of a house encircled by pencils - Bitcoin Foundations

Imagine trying to trade pencils for a house. The owner of the house may not need two million pencils and you could not acquire fractions of a house. In the example given, each individual pencil has a relatively small value (much less than most goods or services). You can trade one pencil, a dozen pencils, or two million pencils. It doesn’t really matter. But if the homeowner has no need for so many pencils, the trade will not take place.  

On the other hand, a house is not very divisible. Even if the homeowner only needed 30 pencils, you can’t trade just part of a house. A house is typically a large, expensive asset, and it’s not practical to trade a small piece of it. You would have to trade the entire house.

 

Coincidence of Time-frame

Rotting orange in the middle of the road - Bitcoin Foundations

Imagine trying to accumulate enough oranges to trade for a truck. Since the oranges are perishable, by the time you accumulated enough oranges, half your stock would have gone rotten. 

In this example, the orange has a limited lifespan. Each orange that is picked loses its value over time quickly (much quicker than the truck). Healthy delicious oranges are typically more valuable to someone than using rotten ones for compost. By the time you think you have enough oranges saved, you’ll find you have to return to the orange farm to pick more. Depending on how fast or slow you pick your oranges, you may never accumulate enough fresh oranges for the trade. 

Coincidence of Location

Artistic drawing of a factory and a house side by side - Bitcoin Foundations

Imagine trying to trade a factory by a lake for a house in the mountains. Typically, things like factories and houses are immovable. For this trade to occur, you must want a house specifically on that mountain. Not only that, but at the same time your trading partner will have to want a factory on the side of that specific lake. This could happen, but the chances of such a coincidence occurring are very slim and so this trade will likely not take place. 

Solving the Coincidence of wants Problem

Drawing of an apple farmer, banana farmer, and fisherman illustrating the use of bananas as money - Bitcoin Foundations

The coincidence of wants is what money solves, but how did it come to fruition? Did someone invent “money” or has it always been around? Lets use an example to help understand this.

Bob wants to trade his apples for Alice’s fish. The problem is Alice is allergic to apples and doesn’t want any of Bob’s apples. Bob overhears that Alice really likes bananas, but bob doesn’t have any. Luckily, Bob knows Mark, who owns a banana plantation. Bob goes to Mark to trade his Apples for Mark’s Bananas. Bob then uses these newly acquired bananas to trade for Alice’s fish. 

What Happened?

Bob acquired the bananas purely for the purpose of acquiring another good (in this case Alice’s fish). In this instance, he used bananas as money. We have Consumption Goods which are goods we consume, such as bread for nutrition. We have Capital Goods which are goods we use to perform a task, such as using a car to drive from one place to another. We have Monetary Goods which are goods that we acquire for the sole purpose of acquiring other goods. This is commonly referred to as a medium of exchange. Money is the medium that is used to trade the goods or services we actually want. 

“Money is a good that is purely used for exchange later on for other goods and services. It’s a market good like any other”
Artistic drawing of Saifedean Ammous - Bitcoin Foundations
Saifedean Ammous
Economist
The importance here is that money can be any market good. Historically there was no one person or institution that established what was considered money or what wasn’t. A medium of exchange will develop organically in any economy greater than 10 people The good that was most easily accepted in any single economy was the one that was used as money. Saleability is another way to describe the ease of acceptance i.e. the good that was most easily sold (most saleable) would be used as money.3 This was a recursive story. The monetary good had value because people accepted it, and people accepted it because it had value. 
"The key property that leads to a good being adopted freely as money on the market is saleability"
Artistic impression of Carl Menger - Bitcoin Foundations
Carl Menger
Economist

In our next article, we’ll go through the evolution of money and discuss some historical examples of what occurred with primitive money. 

References

  1. Investopedia. Barter System vs. Currency System: An Overview. Investopedia. Available at: https://www.investopedia.com/ask/answers/061615/what-difference-between-barter-and-currency-systems.asp [accessed 25 November 2022]
  2. Szabo N. Shelling Out: The Origins of Money. Nakamoto Institute. 2002. Available from: https://nakamotoinstitute.org/shelling-out/ [accessed 25 November 2022]
  3. Menger, C. (1892). On the Origin of Money. Economic Journal, 2, 239-255. 

These articles were designed to make these concepts more palatable. If you’re interested in reading a more in-depth perspective on the concept of money, consider the following:

Robert Breedlove, “Money, Bitcoin and Time Saifedean Ammous, “The Bitcoin Standard: A Decentralised Alternative to Central Banking”. Wiley, 2018
Vijay Boyapati, “The Bullish Case for Bitcoin” 
Robert Breedlove, “Masters and Slaves of Money
Nick Szabo, “Shelling Out: The Origins of Money

A picture of Ruki, a doctor with a special interest in Bitcoin education - Bitcoin Foundations

Ruki is a passionate Bitcoin educator who firmly believes in the principles of the Austrian School of Economics. As a sound money advocate he recognises its benefits to individuals and society as a whole. He is dedicated to empowering those without financial access to take control and build a more secure future.